Sunday 24th of November 2024

the business of rent-seeking .....

the business of rent-seeking .....

What is rent? You don't make it past the elementary economics class unless you know that's a trick question. In economics there are two kinds of rent: common or garden rent and ''economic rent''.

Obviously, ordinary rent is what you pay for the use of a building or land. By contrast, economic rent (also called quasi rent) is the amount paid for any ''factor of production'' - land, labour or capital - in excess of the amount it needs to be paid to keep it in its present use (which is its ''opportunity cost'').

If you think you've never heard of economic rent before, you're probably wrong - unless you haven't heard of the minerals resource rent tax or of ''rent-seeking''.

It doesn't get talked about a lot, but economic rent is widespread in every real-world economy, making it something worth talking about. You never know, you may be getting a bit yourself (I'm getting loads).

Economic rent isn't a cost of production that contributes to the selling price of the factor - the land, the physical capital or the labour. Rather, it's earnings to the owner of the factor determined by the selling price. Economic rent is equivalent to ''producer surplus'' in the market for goods and services. When it's received by a business it's also known as ''above-normal profits'' or ''super profits'' (does that term ring a bell?).

Economists define profit differently to accountants. To an accountant, profit is sales revenue minus actual costs. To an economist, costs involve actual costs plus the opportunity cost of the financial capital invested in the business - that is, the most the capital would earn in a different industry with an equivalent degree of risk. (For unincorporated businesses, the opportunity cost also includes the highest wage the proprietor could earn in a different job.)

The opportunity cost of the capital invested in the business is what economists call ''normal profit''. Any actual profit in excess of actual costs plus normal profit is above-normal profit and likely to be the consequence of economic rents.

What is it that allows some factors of production to earn economic rent - higher returns than those needed to keep them in the business? Scarcity or, better, exclusivity. The factor possesses some highly desirable characteristic that means there's not enough of it to go around, so people fight over it and, in the process, bid up its price.

In a textbook economy such a situation wouldn't last long because the market would have an incentive to increase the supply of the desirable factor to meet the high demand. In real-world economies, economic rents can persist because they're not easily replicated. The supply of harbourside land, for instance, is fixed.

The exclusivity of factors may be natural or contrived. Governments often create economic rents by limiting the number of licences they're willing to issue to participants in particular industries - taxi plates, for example.

Patents and copyright are designed to allow creators to enjoy economic rents for a fixed period. This implies monopoly profits are a form of economic rent, although rents can be enjoyed by more than one firm in an industry.

And don't forget many workers benefit from rents. Unions may be able to limit the supply of a particular occupation and so force wages above what they would otherwise be.

In this, however, trade unions are amateurs compared with the colleges of medical specialists.

But some rents aren't contrived. If I were prepared to do my job for $60,000 a year but my boss paid me $100,000, I'd be enjoying economic rent of $40,000 a year. Why would he pay me more than my ''reservation wage''? Because if he didn't a rival employer would.

Of course, the people who do best in the rent stakes are film stars, sports stars and the like. Such people have far more talent than the rest of us, but they also a have a name - are a brand - that attracts more customers than other actors or players do.

The point of all this is that, from a social (community-wide) point of view, economic rent is a waste - a ''dead-weight loss,'' as economists say. It's a price customers pay that does nothing to increase the production of goods and services. If we could eliminate it - say by taxing it away - it wouldn't reduce production, just the incomes of the owners of scarce resources.

This, of course, is the justification for the minerals resource rent tax. There's a lot of economic rent associated with the exploitation of mineral deposits, particularly in Australia, because world reserves of certain minerals are relatively limited and because much of our reserves is high quality and easily won.

Since these resources belong to us, not the mining companies we permit to extract them, we would be mugs not to tax much of that rent rather than letting largely foreign companies walk away with most of it.

I hope by now you understand why the Abbott government's talk of all the damage the mining tax is doing to the economy is tosh, intended to mislead the economically undereducated. (Which is not to say Labor's tax was well designed - it wasn't.)

It's rational for workers to be ''rent-seekers'' in the sense that they equip themselves with scarce skills and work hard at being the best in their field. Similarly, it's rational for firms to seek out niches where prices far exceed costs.

But that's not what the term ''rent-seeker'' - which comes from the libertarian ''public choice theory'' - is usually taken to mean. It refers to groups that lobby the government for tax, spending or regulatory policies that benefit the lobbyists at the expense of taxpayers or consumers, or their rivals.

As The Economist magazine puts it in its business dictionary, it means ''cutting yourself a bigger slice of the cake rather than making the cake bigger''.

Who's Taxing Who & Who Pays The Rent?

 

legal battle over sources...

Western Australia's Supreme Court has ordered Gina Rinehart's company, Hancock Prospecting, to pay the costs incurred by a Fairfax journalist in a legal battle over sources.

Ms Rinehart had taken action against senior Fairfax business writer Adele Ferguson.

She had tried to subpoena Ms Ferguson to produce recordings, texts, notes and emails.

Ms Rinehart's lawyers had argued the material was required for a private arbitration hearing in New South Wales.

But the subpoena was set aside by consent, with no substantive hearing, although there were five short directions hearings in chambers.

In arguing against costs, the company's lawyers said the application did not involve complexity because proceedings last year involving subpoenas served on West Australian Newspapers (WAN) and journalist Steve Pennells had resolved questions regarding media shield laws in WA.

But in her special costs order, Justice Janine Pritchard said Ms Ferguson's costs should be paid by Hancock Prospecting.

She said that while the costs were substantial, the meaning and operation of WA's shield laws did involve novel and complex questions.

The laws were tested in court last year, after Gina Rinehart brought separate proceedings against WAN and Pennells, who had written a series of articles about a legal stoush between the mining magnate and most of her children.

After a hearing in May, only the subpoena directed to WAN was being pursued by Hancock Prospecting, although the effect on Pennells and his ability to work as a journalist would have been the same.

Justice Pritchard found Pennells was protected by Western Australia's shield laws, and could not be compelled to reveal his sources.

She said the subpoena should be set aside "on the ground that it is oppressive and an abuse of process".

She found "the disclosure of the evidence would constitute a breach of a fundamental ethical obligation on Steve Pennells as a journalist".

http://www.abc.net.au/news/2014-03-15/rinehart-ordered-to-pay-journalist27s-costs/5323084